Pages

Pages

Pages

Sunday, January 31, 2021

Covid is a pathetic prelude to the next act

Planetary Jeopardy. Ishi Nobu, Jan. 2, 2021



 

A mass extinction event is well underway, propagated by a burgeoning human population which has raped Nature with technological marvels in the name of ‘progress’. The graphs below show an exponential trend in human environmental impact.



 

There were less than 300 million hectares of croplands in 1600. Now over 1.5 billion hectares are plowed and planted.

 



 

Over 75% of the land on Earth has been scarred by human activity. 97% of the biologically richest ecosystems have been grievously damaged by humans. Yet deforestation continues, especially in tropical forests with the most abundant wildlife left on Earth.

There are over 65 million kilometers of roads crisscrossing the world’s lands. The very existence of these ribbons of death slices habitats into fragments, foreclosing viable lives for many animals. From an environmental perspective, what travels on these roads is pollution incarnate.

Shipping is the lifeblood of economic globalization. Over 60,000 colossal ships crisscross ocean trade routes, burning 2.2+ billion barrels of the foulest possible fuel. Besides massively polluting the oceans and killing large marine mammals, ships contribute ~2.5% of global greenhouse gas emissions.

Mass extinction is picking up pace. Vertebrate populations – amphibians, fish, reptiles, birds, and mammals – plummeted by an average 70% in the past 4 decades.

The decline in global insect populations has been even steeper, owing mostly to pesticides. As insects pollinate many plants and are voluminously significant in the animal food chain, their decimation is a harbinger for larger animal species, as well as spelling a decline for the multitude of crops which require pollination.

The extent of wildfires in Siberia and the western United States this year have been unprecedented. The burning will only worsen as time wears on. The toll will be further biosphere loss, an acceleration in warming, and an addition to air pollution.



 

The oceans are dying as well as the land. Coral reefs are home to 25% of the ocean’s fish. Those fish are food for much other sea life which doesn’t live there. 80% of the world’s coral reefs have died since their global peak in the mid-20th century. The rest will be gone by 2030.

As with greenhouse gas emissions, the pace of global warming is increasing in a nonlinear way. Climate modelers have been too conservative in their estimates. The worst-case scenario modelers have put out best matches what has gone on this century. It’s going to be a lot hotter sooner than climate modelers have let on.

The most salient – and little appreciated – fact about global warming is that there is an approximate 40-year lag between emissions and atmospheric hotting up. This owes to oceans absorbing ~95% of the initial warmth from greenhouse gas emissions. Essentially, the global atmospheric temperature now owes to emissions in the 1980s.

By 2060, average global air surface temperature is likely to be 4.8 °C above the 1880 benchmark. The hotter parts of the planet – notably portions of southern Asia and Africa – will be uninhabitable for humans by that time.

Global warming alone would be enough wipe out much life on Earth. The rape of Nature otherwise simply ensures more extinction.

A growing scarcity of drinking water, and an increase in global hunger and poverty, are already happening. Harvests peaked worldwide in the mid-1990s. Yields have declined since. The combination of more severe storms, drought, and sporadic flooding are only going to further reduce agricultural production and raise food prices. There is no turnaround in sight for this trend.

Humanity’s ecological wallop is obviously unsustainable. Let’s consider what might be done to ameliorate the damage.

The most significant fact about the mass extinction event underway is its extent. The scale is staggering.

What that means is that piecemeal measures will prove wholly inadequate. Planting trees as a supposed amelioration to deforestation is a childish publicity stunt – only illustrative of how optimistically ignorant people are. Ecosystems aren’t refurbished by planting trees.

A ridiculous notion that will be increasingly brought up to address global warming is geoengineering. This is about as savvy as the “better living through chemistry” program of the post-WW2 era that begat the burgeoning production of pesticides and plastic.

Technology cannot fix what technology created. Not only is it infeasible and inadequate, it’s way too late to make any difference. Technology cannot bring dead creatures back to life, restore ecosystems, or even reverse the intricate dynamics of biospheric degradation that humanity committed itself to – for the luxury of more convenient or adventurous lives and the greedy accumulation of riches by the relative few.

The last refuge of climate deniers was that humans simply could not make that big a dent on the global environment. Geoengineers are on the opposite end of that silly spectrum in thinking that machines can put into reverse on a planetary scale what is accelerating in fast forward.

Another foolhardy endeavor is the promotion of “clean” energy. There is no such thing as clean energy. Taking more from Nature to generate more electricity is not environmental friendliness, even if it does lessen the extraction and burning of fossil fuels. More is not less, even if it draws its initial inspiration from the Sun.

In terms of energy, what is most bizarre is that energy conservation is seldom touted nowadays: a signification that humanity has lost any sense of discipline. Along that line, lessening food waste and limiting population growth go unsung as helpful gestures toward self-preservation. Nearly half of the food grown globally goes uneaten.

 

 

 

Wasting less food requires the same sort of societal organization that dealing with the covid-19 pandemic presented – and we know how well that is turning out.

The perils of unbridled population growth had been known long before the 17th century, when Thomas Malthus made himself unpopular by pointing the problem out at the onset of industrialization. Enforcing social distancing to avoid viral contagion is a truly tiny potato compared to stopping adults from indulging the core biological urge of dancing the horizontal tango.

The number of mouths to feed is not going to be a problem for much longer. Instead, the die-off is going to begin in earnest. The census of people on the planet will peak within the next decade or so before staring a precipitous decline.

Now we come to the nut of the problem. If plutocracy abides, not only will inequity and societal injustice continue to thrive, but the body count from it will climb to truly alarming numbers thanks to capitalism’s cumulative environmental toll.

As this brief survey shows, the mass extinction event underway is a systemic dynamic that may only addressed with a systemic solution. And the hour is running late indeed.

The covid pandemic highlights how humanity now collectively responds to a global crisis: panicked, uncoordinated to the point of disorganized, covetous and cantankerously disobedient. Covid is a pathetic prelude to the next act.

The bottom line: the only societies that have any chance of survival are those that adopt eusocialism. Self-sustaining survival cities must be established to ride out the biospheric decimation gathering force.

World civilization will collapse by 2070. Humans will be extinct by the end of the century.


Suggested further reading:

Ishi Nobu, The Fruits of Civilization (2019).

Ishi Nobu, “Environment” essays.

Living planet report 2020,” World Wildlife Federation (2020).

Wednesday, January 27, 2021

CJ & CJ -- CJ Hopkins and Caitlin Johnstone.... oh, and MJ too

That’s All Folks!
Authored (mostly satirically) by CJ Hopkins via The Consent Factory. Jan.24, 2021.

As they used to say at the end of all those wacky Looney Tunes cartoons, that’s all folks! The show is over. Literal Russian-Asset Hitler, the Latest Greatest Threat to Western Democracy, the Monster of Mar-a-Lago, Trumpzilla, Trumpenstein, the Ayatollah of Orange Shinola, has finally been humiliated and given the bum-rush out of Washington by the heroic forces of the GloboCap “Resistance,” with a little help from the US military. The whole thing went exactly to script.

Well … OK, not quite exactly to script. Despite four years of dire warnings by the corporate media, the Intelligence Community, Hollywood celebrities, the Democratic Party, faux anti-fascists, fake-Left pundits, and pretty much every utterly deluded, Trump-obsessed liberal with an Internet connection, there was no Hitlerian “Reichstag Fire,” no Boogaloo, no Civil War II, no coup, no white-supremacist uprising. Nothing. The man simply got on a chopper and was flown away to his Florida resort.

I know, you’re probably thinking … 
“Wow, how embarrassing for the GloboCap ‘Resistance,’ being exposed as a bunch of utterly shameless, neo-Goebbelsian propagandists, and liars, and hysterical idiots, and such!” 
And, in any other version of reality, you’d have a point … but not in this one.

No, in this reality, “Democracy Has Prevailed!” Yes, it was touch and go there for a while, as there was no guarantee that the Intelligence Community, the military-industrial complex, Western governments, the corporate media, supranational corporations, Internet oligarchs, and virtually every other component of the global-capitalist empire could keep one former game show host with no real political power whatsoever from taking over the entire world.

Still, Trump’s failure to go full-Hitler, or even half-Hitler, was somewhat awkward. I mean, you can’t whip millions of people into a four-year frenzy of fear and hatred of a clearly powerless ass-clown president, and portray him as a Russian Intelligence asset, and the Son of Hitler, and all the rest of it, and then just drop the act cold and laugh in their faces. That would leave them feeling like total morons who had just spent the last four years of their lives being lied to and emotionally manipulated, or like members of a cult, or something.

Fortunately, for GloboCap, this was not a major problem. All they had to do was produce a cheap simulation of “Trump going full-Hitler.” It didn’t even have to be convincing. They just needed a semi-dramatic event to plug into the official narrative, something they could call “an attempted coup,” “an insurrection,” “an attack,” and so on, and which millions of credulous liberals could hysterically shriek about on the Internet.

The “Storming of the Capitol” did the trick.

They held a dress rehearsal in Berlin last August, and then gave the real performance in the Capitol Building (this time it was for all the money, so they went ahead and got a couple people killed). It wasn’t very hard to pull off. All they actually had to do, in both Berlin and DC, was allow a small fringe group of angry protesters to gain access to the building, film it, and then pump out the “attempted coup” narrative. It made no difference whatsoever that the “domestic terrorists” (in both Berlin and Washington) were a completely unorganized, unarmed mob that posed absolutely zero threat of “staging a coup” and “overthrowing the government.” It also made not the slightest difference that Trump didn’t actually “incite” the mob (yes, I put myself through the agony of reading every word of his speech, which was the usual word salad from start to finish). We’re talking propaganda here, not reality.

The so-called “Violent Storming of the Capitol” set the stage for the main event, which was the show of force we have all just witnessed. Someone (I’m not entirely clear who) ordered in the troops, tens of thousands of them, locked down Washington, erected fences, set up road blocks and military check points, and otherwise occupied the government district. It looked like any other US-military post-“regime-change” occupation, because that’s what it was, which was precisely the point. As I have been repeating for … well, for over four years now, it was always going to end this way, with GloboCap making an example of Trump and reminding everyone who is really in charge.

Look, let’s be clear about these last four years, because there are all kinds of crazy theories going around (not to mention the official GloboCap narrative), but what actually happened is pretty simple. Here’s the whole story, as concise as I can make it.
Back in 2016, the American people, sick to the gills of global capitalism and its increasingly oppressive woke ideology, elected an unauthorized, narcissistic ass-clown to the highest office in the land. They did this for a variety of reasons, but mostly it was just a big “fuck you” to the establishment. It was an act of rebellion against a government which they know is owned by unaccountable, supranational corporations and oligarchs who openly detest them. It was an act of rebellion against a system of government they know they have no influence over, and are not going to have any influence over. It was an act of rebellion against global capitalism, the unopposed, global-hegemonic system which has dominated the world for the last thirty years … whether they realized what they were rebelling against or not.

This act of rebellion happened on the heels of Brexit (another such act of rebellion) and in the context of the rise of assorted “populist” movements all throughout the world. When Trump actually won in 2016, the global capitalist ruling classes realized they had a serious problem … a “populist” rebellion in the heart of the empire. So they suspended the Global War on Terror and launched the War on Populism.

The ultimate objective of the War on Populism was to neutralize this “populist” rebellion and remind the public who is actually running things. Think of the Trump era as a prison riot. In any maximum security prison, the prisoners know they can’t escape, but they can definitely raise a little hell now and then, which they tend to do when they get really tired of being abused and neglected by the prison guards. Most prison riots run out of steam on their own, but if they go on too long or get too ugly, the penal authorities typically respond by shooting a few prisoners (usually the ringleaders), and reminding the inmates that they are in a prison, and that the owners of the prison have guns, whereas they have shivs made out of spoons and toothbrushes.

This, basically, is what we’ve just experienced. The global capitalist ruling classes have just reminded us who is really in charge, who the US military answers to, and how quickly they can strip away the facade of democracy and the rule of law. They have reminded us of this for the last ten months, by putting us under house arrest, beating and arresting us for not following orders, for not wearing masks, for taking walks without permission, for having the audacity to protest their decrees, for challenging their official propaganda, about the virus, the election results, etc. They are reminding us currently by censoring dissent, and deplatforming anyone they deem a threat to their official narratives and ideology.

In other words, GloboCap is teaching us a lesson. I don’t know how much clearer they could make it. They just installed a new puppet president, who can’t even simulate mental acuity, in a locked-down, military-guarded ceremony which no one was allowed to attend, except for a few members of the ruling classes. They got some epigone of Albert Speer to convert the Mall (where the public normally gathers) into a “field of flags” symbolizing “unity.” They even did the Nazi “Lichtdom” thing. To hammer the point home, they got Lady Gaga to dress up as a Hunger Games character with a “Mockingjay” brooch and sing the National Anthem. They broadcast this spectacle to the entire world.

And the lesson isn’t quite over yet … it won’t be over for a while. The “War on Populism” will simply morph into the “New Normal War on Domestic Terror,” which will become one more theater in the “Global War on Terror,” which has been on hiatus, and which will now resume. As I have pointed out repeatedly over the past four years, we appear to be headed toward a dystopian future in which there will essentially be two classes of people: (a) “normals” (i.e., those who conform to global-capitalist ideology and decrees); and (b) the “extremists” (i.e., those who don’t).

It will make no difference whatsoever what type of “extremists” these “extremists” are … religious-fundamentalist extremists, Islamic extremists, Christian extremists, right-wing extremists, left-wing extremists, white-supremacist or Black-nationalist extremists, virus deniers, anti-vaxxers, conspiracy theorists, anti-maskers, recalcitrant transphobians, anti-transhumanists, pronoun resisters, defiant oppositionalists, or whatever … the names don’t really matter. The point is, conform or be labelled an “extremist,” a “domestic terrorist,” or some other type of “antisocial person” or “social deviant,” or “potential threat to public health.”

I don’t claim to know every detail, but one thing seems abundantly clear. We are not going back to the way things were. GloboCap has been explaining this to us, over and over, for almost a year. They couldn’t have made it any more explicit. When they warned us to get ready because a “New Normal” was coming, they meant it.

And now … well … here it is.



Be Your Own Revolution. Caitlin Johnstone. Jan. 27, 2021.

I made the mistake of involving myself in a sectarian Twitter spat when I was halfway through my morning coffee today and I instantly felt like an idiot.

People from the Left Twitter faction I’d offended rushed in to push back against the offense I’d caused them, and within minutes I felt it: the all-too familiar sensation of inspiration and creativity draining away from my body. Tension, coldness and defensiveness where previously there was playfulness and the crackling sensation of an exciting new day in which anything was possible.

If you’re active online, you’ve probably experienced this too. The days when you’re involved in sectarian bickering are the days when you are at your least creative, your least inspired, and your least effective at fighting against the machine. At best the drama gives your ego a tickle (as social media platforms are designed to do), after which you feel a bit yuck. The longer you engage in it, the lower the probability that you will produce something creative and inspired that day.

As a general rule, you may find that it works best to reject cliques and factions altogether. When you “belong” to any group you feel compelled to defend it, and to move with it wherever it goes even if that’s not where you feel like the energy is. You get invested in wanting the collective to move in a certain direction, and you get frustrated when it just wants to focus on silly nonsense and sectarian feuds.

So my advice to you here, which you of course can take or leave, is to just blast off on your own and fight your own revolution in your own way.

The unfortunate fact is that our society is insane, and its madness pervades literally every political faction to varying degrees. Marrying yourself to any group means marrying its madness. Instead, focus on becoming more sane, and then act based on that sanity.

Just blast off. Don’t wait for your comrades. Don’t try to pull them along with you before they are ready. Just blast forward into your own revolution, burning brightly and scorching the machine with your own light. If you shine brightly enough, the others may follow when they are ready.

One of the most frustrating things is seeing where we need to move and not being able to get the collective to come with you. You’re like, “It’s there! Let’s move!”, and they just want to bicker and ego spar. Just blast off into health yourself, and trust that the others will follow if and when they are able.

Be your own revolution. You have all the media access you need to help wake the world up with the power of your own inspired action. Reject cliques, factions and sectarianism, and have the courage to stand on your own two feet attacking the machine with your own unique abilities.

This doesn’t mean you can’t organize and work collectively; you absolutely can. If you see people doing something you want to uplift, uplift it. But when you’re done, don’t stay and become a member of the club. Move on and retain your self-sovereignty. If you’re doing something that people want to help uplift and amplify, let them do so. When they don’t want to anymore, let them go. Don’t try to manipulate them into staying.

You are free to collaborate with anyone on any issue at any time. You don’t actually need to be a member of the Blah Blah Whateverist Club to do this. And when nothing is happening that you want to collaborate with others on, you can attack the machine on your own, using your own unique set of tools based on your own inspiration. You are not owned or bound.

All these debates we’re seeing lately over who should be let into and kept out of the Revolution Club, how the Revolution Club should act, who should lead the Revolution Club etc are based on the assumption that there has to be a Revolution Club in the first place, and there just doesn’t. Organize and collaborate on a case-by-case, issue-by-issue basis while remaining sovereign.

Have the compassion to prioritize the needs of the collective and the courage to stand as an individual. Trying to impose your will on exactly how the collective revolution should and should not be moving is a doomed endeavor, because you cannot control the collective, you can only control yourself. So be your own revolution and attack the machine wherever you detect a weak point in its armor.

I’ve avoided all cliques and factions like the plague, and I’ve been far more effective in this fight than I would have been if I’d chosen to glom onto some faction and uphold all its -ists and -isms. It would have killed my ability to move with agility in whatever way is demanded by each present moment, because I would have been binding myself to the movements of a group that isn’t seeing what I’m seeing and can’t move the way I move.

This is just what’s worked for me, and of course your mileage may vary. But if you’re like me and you don’t see the various groups, organizations and factions getting us to where we need to go, consider stepping out of the vehicle, standing on your own two feet, and waging your own revolution.





....

What it will lead to is The Great Bifurcation, the 3rd Scenario I posited in The Jackpot Chronicles. Much has come into focus now since I wrote that just this past summer.

If The Great Reset comes about, and I think it’s already here, it will lead to that two tier society where the world’s underclass are governed algorithmically via smartphones, digital, programmable scrip (UBI) and well ordered dopamine hits. Meanwhile the far smaller populace that actually owns all the assets globally live in a parallel universe where they retain agency, freedom of movement, diet, and thought.

On my mailing list I talk about what we can do as individuals to try and get clear of The Great Reset. Because even if we loathe this with every fibre of our being, find it oppressive and tyrannical, anti-human, anti-spirit and soulless, we won’t be able to do anything about it from the wrong side of the impermeable membrane that will very soon cordon off the haves from the haves-nots.

We have to defend our liberties, our civil rights and our assets in the New Normal. In a worst case scenario it’ll require forming an underground network a la Isaac Assimov’s Foundation. The Foundation’s stated purpose was to survive the onset of a Galactic Dark Age and preserve the accumulated culture and wisdom of a civilization that had irrevocably embarked on a path that would trigger its own demise.

Now more than ever it is important we all try to improve things from the grass roots level as the Stakeholder Capitalism rubric may be the last gasp of a system about to come off the rails completely or after a prolonged period of disruption and tyranny.

Saturday, January 23, 2021

Bradshaw et al: Ghastly Future

Expert prognosis for the planet – we’re on track for a ghastly futureCorey J. A. Bradshaw. January 13, 2021.


An international group of 17 leading scientists have produced a comprehensive yet concise assessment of the state of civilization, warning that the outlook is more dire and dangerous than is generally understood.

A loss of biodiversity and accelerating climate change in the coming decades coupled with ignorance and inaction is threatening the survival of all species, including our very own, according to the experts from institutions including Stanford University, UCLA, and Flinders University.

The researchers state that world leaders need a ‘cold shower’ regarding the state of our environment both to plan and act to avoid a ghastly future.

Read original article
Download original article (pdf)

Lead author Professor Corey Bradshaw of Flinders University in Australia says he and his colleagues have summarized the state of the natural world in stark form to help clarify the gravity of the human predicament.

“Humanity is causing a rapid loss of biodiversity and, with it, Earth’s ability to support complex life. But the mainstream is having difficulty grasping the magnitude of this loss, despite the steady erosion of the fabric of human civilization,” Professor Bradshaw says.

“In fact, the scale of the threats to the biosphere and all its lifeforms is so great that it is difficult to grasp for even well-informed experts. The problem is compounded by ignorance and short-term self-interest, with the pursuit of wealth and political interests stymying the action that is crucial for survival,” he says.

Professor Paul Ehrlich of Stanford University says that no political or economic system, or leadership, is prepared to handle the predicted disasters, or even capable of such action.

“Stopping biodiversity loss is nowhere close to the top of any country’s priorities, trailing far behind other concerns such as employment, healthcare, economic growth, or currency stability. While it is positive news that President-elect Biden intends to reengage the US in Paris Climate accord within his first 100 days of office, it is a minuscule gesture given the scale of the challenge. Humanity is running an ecological Ponzi scheme in which society robs nature and future generations to pay for short-term economic enhancement today”.

“Most economies operate on the basis that counteraction now is too costly to be politically palatable. Combined with disinformation campaigns to protect short-term profits it is doubtful that the scale of changes we need will be made in time,” Professor Ehrlich says.

Professor Dan Blumstein from UCLA says the scientists are choosing to speak boldly and fearlessly because life literally depends on it. “What we are saying might not be popular, and indeed is frightening. But we need to be candid, accurate, and honest if humanity is to understand the enormity of the challenges we face in creating a sustainable future. Without political will backed by tangible action that scales to the enormity of the problems facing us, the added stresses to human health, wealth, and well-being will perversely diminish our political capacity to mitigate the erosion of the Earth’s life-support system upon which we all depend. Human population growth and consumption continues to escalate, and we’re still more focused on expanding human enterprise than we are on devising and implementing solutions to critical issues such as biodiversity loss. By the time we fully comprehend the impact of ecological deterioration, it will be too late. Without fully appreciating and broadcasting the scale of the problems and the enormity of the solutions required, society will fail to achieve even modest sustainability goals, and catastrophe will surely follow”.

The experts say their ‘perspective’ paper, which cites more than 150 studies, seeks to outline clearly and unambiguously the likely future trends in biodiversity decline, mass extinction, climate disruption, planetary toxification, all tied to human consumption and population growth to demonstrate the near certainty that these problems will worsen over the coming decades, with negative impacts for centuries to come. It also explains the impact of political impotence and the ineffectiveness of current and planned actions to address the ominous scale of environmental erosion.Summary of major environmental-change categories expressed as percentage relative to the baseline given in the text. Red indicates the percentage of the category that is damaged, lost, or otherwise affected, whereas blue indicates the percentage that is intact, remaining, or otherwise unaffected.


Prof Corey J. A. Bradshaw: Global Ecology, College of Science and Engineering, Flinders University; Australian Research Council Centre of Excellence for Australian Biodiversity and Heritage, EpicAustralia.org
Prof Paul R. Ehrlich: Department of Biology, Stanford University, USA
Prof Daniel T. Blumstein: Department of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology and the Institute of the Environment and Sustainability, University of California, Los Angeles, USA
Emeritus Prof Andrew Beattie: Department of Biological Sciences, Macquarie University, Australia
Dr Gerardo Ceballos: Institute of Ecology, National Autonomous University of Mexico, Mexico
Emeritus Associate Prof Eileen Crist: Department of Science, Technology, and Society, Virginia Tech, USA
Joan Diamond: Millennium Alliance for Humanity and the Biosphere, Stanford University, USA
Prof Rodolfo Dirzo: Department of Biology, Stanford University, USA
Emeritus Dr Anne H. Ehrlich: Department of Biology, Stanford University, USA
Prof John Harte: Energy and Resources Group, University of California, Berkeley, USA; The Rocky Mountain Biological Laboratory, USA
Dr Mary Ellen Harte: The Rocky Mountain Biological Laboratory, USA
Prof Graham Pyke: Department of Biology, Stanford University, USA; The Rocky Mountain Biological Laboratory, USA
Dr Peter H. Raven: Missouri Botanical Garden, USA
Prof William J. Ripple: Department of Forest Ecosystems and Society, Oregon State University, USA
Dr Frédérik Saltré: Global Ecology, College of Science and Engineering, Flinders University; Australian Research Council Centre of Excellence for Australian Biodiversity and Heritage, EpicAustralia.org
Dr Christine Turnbull: Department of Biological Sciences, Macquarie University, Australia
Dr Mathis Wackernagel: Global Footprint Network, USA

Original article: Underestimating the challenges of avoiding a ghastly future


Sunday, January 17, 2021

Blair Fix on moving to a non-growth world

Living the good life in a non-growth world: Investigating the role of hierarchy. Blair Fix. Jan. 5, 2021.


This is the first of two essays written for (and supported by) the Seoul Platform for Initiating Discourses on an Equitable and Resilient Society. These essays investigate the role that hierarchy plays in driving inequality and unsustainability. This piece introduces the facts of hierarchy. The second (long-form) essay will look at how these facts relate to ‘living the good life in a non-growth world’.


Sustainability or bust

For the past 200 years, humanity has conducted an unintended experiment. The (tacit) research question is this: how much of the Earth’s resources can one species consume? We have yet to find out the answer … nor do we want to.

By nearly all indicators, humanity is doing immense damage to the biosphere. We are using non-renewable resources at a feverish pace [1]. We may be causing the Earth’s sixth mass extinction [2]. And perhaps most alarmingly, we are changing the climate in a way that could put civilization at risk [3]. It is time, then, for our unintended experiment to stop. Instead of plumbing the depths of unsustainability, we must do the opposite. Humanity must become sustainable. The question is, how?

In one sense, the answer is simple. Our impact on the environment is a function of two things: (1) how many people there are; and (2) the amount of resources each person consumes [4]. Becoming sustainable is therefore easy in principle. It requires reducing the human population and reducing resource consumption per person. And yet beneath this simple formula is a web of complexity (and confusion). Here, I will ignore population reduction (which is itself controversial). I will focus on achieving sustainability by reducing per capita resource use.

Mainstream discussions of sustainability tend to focus on efficiency [5,6]. If we can use resources more efficiently, the thinking goes, we will lessen our environmental impact. The problem, though, is that there is little evidence that this is true. Our energy conversion technologies, for instance, have been getting more efficient for two centuries [7]. Yet this greater efficiency has not caused us to consume fewer energy resources. Instead, we are using more than ever. In fact, it may be that efficiency is a primary driver of resource consumption. The reason is simple: more efficient technology tends to lower costs, which then makes resources cheaper. And so we consume more of them [8].

Outside the mainstream, more emphasis is put on directly reducing resource use by consuming less. This thinking goes by many names, but here I will refer to it as ‘degrowth’. The idea is that instead of pursuing economic growth, we should learn how to live with less. We should voluntarily ‘degrow’ the economy [9,10].

My view is that degrowth is the only sound option for becoming sustainable. I will leave aside the question of how much we need to degrow. Instead, I will focus on how we can consume less while creating a society that is equitable and just.


The human need for equity

A sustainable future need not be equitable. That is because our impact on the Earth is a function of the average resource use per person. To the Earth, it doesn’t matter if we use resources equitably, or if one person consumes almost everything and the rest of us starve. It does, however, matter to humans.

There is little that is so toxic to human welfare as rampant inequality. When inequality increases, human well-being gets worse [1113]. This is perhaps one of the most robust findings of the last few decades of social science. In the landscape of neoliberal politics, it is a finding that is surprising. But in the landscape of human evolution, it is not. Humans are a social species. As such, our welfare is inseparable from our relations with others. If these relations are unequal, those at the bottom do worse — regardless of their absolute standard of living. This is not a quirk, but rather a feature we share with other primates [14]. Among social animals, relationships matter.

Assuming we want an equitable society, how can we achieve it while consuming less? Because voluntary degrowth remains largely untested, there are no definitive answers. But I think there are hints. What I will explore, in this essay, is how resource use and equity both relate to hierarchy.

Hierarchy — the ranking of individuals — is part of most social species [1419]. Humans, however, take this form of organization to a new level. We are unique among animals in having developed an explicit chain of command in which power flows from superior to subordinates. This chain of command allows large human groups to function cohesively in a way that no animal group can [20]. But hierarchical organization comes at a cost. Hierarchy concentrates power, and that leads to despotism and inequality. Less intuitively, hierarchy also appears to be energy intensive. As we organize in larger hierarchies, we tend to consume more energy.

In this introductory essay, I will focus on the facts of hierarchy. I will show how hierarchy relates to energy use and to inequality. In the long-form essay to follow, I will explore how these facts pertain to ‘living the good life in a non-growth world’.


Energizing hierarchy1

That humans organize in hierarchy is a fact that should surprise no one. Our working lives are dominated by taking and giving orders [22]. What many people do not know, however, is that hierarchy has a direction — towards more of it.

This trend is recent. Only in the last two centuries has hierarchy grown significantly. While the exact reasons for this growth remain poorly understood, what we can say (with reasonable certainty) is that hierarchy is connected to energy.

I will make the case for this energy-hierarchy connection using indirect evidence. (I do so because direct data for the growth of hierarchy does not yet exist.) The first strand of evidence comes from institution size. As energy use increases, institutions tend to become larger. Figure 1 shows the trend for business firms. In the main panel, each dot represents a country. I have plotted the country’s average firm size (measured in terms of the number of employees) on the vertical axis, and energy use per capita on the horizontal axis. The trend is clear: as countries use more energy, firms tend to get larger.

Figure 1: As countries use more energy, firms get larger. The main panel shows how average firm size (within countries) changes with energy use per capita. Color indicates a country’s energy quartile. I have labelled countries using alpha-3 codes. The inset plot shows the firm size distribution within each respective energy quartile. [Sources and methods].


What we cannot tell, by looking at averages, is how this firm growth happens. It could be that the average grows because most firms get slightly larger. It turns out, however, that this is not what happens. As energy use increases, most firms remain small. Instead, average firm size grows because a few large firms get larger still.

We can see this trend in the inset panel in Figure 1. Here I plot the size distribution of firms across countries, grouped by energy quartile. (In the main plot, I have used color to indicate each quartile.) The horizontal axis shows firms size, while the vertical axis shows the portion of firms that are the corresponding size. What is important here are two things. First, most firms are small — and this remains so regardless of energy use. Second, what changes with energy is the number of large firms. More energy means more large firms. It is a rich-get-richer dynamic. Most firms stay small, but a few large ones grow larger still.

Similar trends hold for government. As countries use more energy, government tends to grow larger. For a thorough review of the energy-institution-size evidence, see [23].

The firm-size evidence hints that hierarchy grows with energy use. Here is the reasoning. From our working lives, we know that firms are hierarchically organized. Therefore, as firms grow larger, it follows that hierarchy increases. This, I believe, is sound logic. But is there evidence that it is true?

Figure 2 shows one strand of evidence that confirms our reasoning. Here, I look at the how the managers’ share of employment relates to energy use. The idea is that the relative number of managers provides a window into the amount of hierarchy in a society. The reason is simple: a manager’s job is to command others. It is a job that, without hierarchy, could not exist. So the growth of managers is indirect evidence for the growth of hierarchy.

Figure 2: As countries use more energy, the relative number of managers increases. Each line represents the path through time of a country. The black line is the smoothed trend across all countries. I have labelled select countries with their alpha-3 codes. [Sources and methods].


What Figure 2 shows is that the relative number of managers tends to grow with energy use. Note, however, that the energy-manager trend is nonlinear. As energy use increases, the relative number of managers grows rapidly at first, but then plateaus.

This non-linear trend, it turns out, is exactly what we expect if hierarchy grows with energy use. The reason has to do with a basic feature of hierarchical organization. In a hierarchy, the number of ranks tends to grow with the logarithm of group size [24]. When a hierarchy is small, adding more members quickly adds more ranks, and hence, more managers. But as the group continues to grow, new ranks are added less rapidly. So the growth of managers slows. Eventually, the hierarchy becomes so large that the portion of people in top ranks becomes constant. The relative number of managers stops growing.

When we formalize this model, it produces the trend shown in Figure 3. Here, black points are the empirical data (the same as in Fig. 2). The rainbow is the model prediction, where color indicates the span of control (how many subordinates each superior controls in a hierarchy). The inset panel shows how the best-fit model compares to the empirical trend. The fit is excellent. The model therefore suggests that managers become more common (as energy use increases) because hierarchy is growing. (See [25] for details about the model.)

Figure 3: A model of the growth of managers. Black points are empirical observations for energy use and the relative number of managers (the same data as in Figure 2). Colored points represent the model results. Color indicates the span of control in the model — the number subordinates controlled by each superior. The inset panel shows how the best-fit model relates to the empirical trend across all countries. [Sources and methods].


To summarize, there is strong (but indirect) evidence that as energy use increases, hierarchy grows. This fact has many implications for sustainability, which I will discuss in the long-form version of this essay. But for now, let’s move on to another feature of hierarchy — its role in driving inequality.


Hierarchical inequality

The fact that humans organize in hierarchies is, in some ways, unsurprising. The social scientist Herbert Simon thought that hierarchy was a fundamental part of all complex systems [26]. Here was his reasoning.

Hierarchy, Simon noted, allows a complex system to be built from simpler components. Cells, for instance, are built from organelles. And multi-cellular organisms, in turn, are built from cells. This hierarchical organization, Simon thought, is how blind evolution can build complex systems. It does so from the bottom up using trial and error.

Hierarchy is also important, Simon proposed, because it centralizes control. The human body, for instance, is not composed of a mass of autonomous cells. Instead, cells surrender their autonomy to the central nervous system — the body’s command center. The advantage is that this hierarchical organization allows complicated behavior like running — something that would be unthinkable if each cell in the body acted independently. But there is one big disadvantage to this concentration of power — despotism.

True, we do not usually think of cells as being despotic. But that is because multicellular organisms have evolved ways to suppress the selfish tendencies of individual cells [27,28]. So unless there is pathology, we never see brain cells using their control over the body for selfish gain.

Among humans, things are different. Like the cells of the body, humans use hierarchy to organize. But unlike our cells, individual humans retain a healthy dose of selfishness. And so when given the chance, individuals inevitably use their hierarchical power to enrich themselves. The result is that hierarchy is a double-edged sword. It is a potent tool for organization. But it is also a pathological tool for despotism and inequality [29].

The evidence for hierarchical inequality is quite straightforward. Within hierarchies, access to resources (i.e. income) tends to grow with control over subordinates. The more subordinates you have, the greater your relative income. Figure 4 shows the evidence. I plot here relative income in a hierarchy against something I call ‘hierarchical power’ — a shorthand for control over subordinates. I define hierarchical power as:
hierarchical power = number of subordinates + 1
The idea here is that everyone starts with a hierarchical power of 1, indicating that they have control over themselves. As you accumulate subordinates, your hierarchical power increases. And, as Figure 4 indicates, so does your income.

Figure 4: Inside hierarchies, relative income grows with hierarchical power. I plot here the relation between relative income (within a hierarchy) and hierarchical power (the number of subordinates + 1). In case-study firms and the US military, I measure income relative to the lowest hierarchical rank. For CEOs, I measure income relative to the firm average. [Sources and methods].


In Figure 4, I plot three different sources of data. Red points come from six case studies of firm hierarchy [30]. Blue points represent the US military (over the last decade). For both the military and case-study firms, each point represents the average income and hierarchical power of a given rank. Green points represent a sample of US CEOs. Each point is an individual CEO [31].

Across a variety of different institutions, it seems that relative income grows with hierarchical power. This suggests that hierarchy is a key driver of inequality [32]. Exactly how hierarchy creates inequality, however, remains poorly understood. In the long-form essay to follow, I will speculate about some of the mechanisms at work.


The sustainable good life

A common thread among degrowth thinkers is that sustainability requires an end to corporate globalism and a transition to community localism. The evidence reviewed here lends credence to this view. The growth of large corporations seems to go hand in hand with using more energy. It makes sense, then, that a reversal towards smaller institutions would help us consume less energy. It is not clear, however, which causes which. Would degrowth energy policy automatically lead to smaller institutions? Or should we focus on making smaller institutions, with energy reduction coming as a side effect? I will investigate these questions in the long-form essay to follow.

And what about inequality? It is tempting to think that if we pursue community localism, inequality will naturally go away. The reasoning is that smaller institutions will have less hierarchy, and hence, less inequality. Unfortunately, this reasoning turns out to be false. The problem (which I will explore in the long-form essay to follow) is that hierarchy is fundamentally non-linear. This means that shrinking large hierarchies has almost no effect on inequality … until the hierarchy has become very small. Pursuing small-scale localism, then, will likely not guarantee equity. Instead, we will need explicit policies for reigning in hierarchical despotism. I will explore these ideas more in the next instalment.


Tuesday, January 12, 2021

Steve Keen: Economic failures of the IPCC process

Economic failures of the IPCC process. Steve Keen. Jan. 12, 2021

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) is the premier international body collating the scientific assessment of climate change, and proposals for mitigation. A joint creation of the United Nations agencies the World Meteorological Organization (WMO) and the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), it brings together scientists from myriad disciplines to assess and summarize the current research on climate change, collating knowledge that is then used to inform governments and politicians. The scientists work on a volunteer basis.

The IPCC relies upon its member governments and “Observers Organizations” to nominate its volunteer authors. This means that, subject to their willingness to volunteer, the most prestigious individuals specialising in climate change in each discipline become the authors of the relevant IPCC chapter for their discipline. They then undertake a review of the peer-reviewed literature in their field (and some non-peer-reviewed work, such as government reports) to distil the current state of knowledge about climate change in their discipline. A laborious review process is also followed, so the draft reports of the volunteer experts is reviewed by other experts in each field, to ensure conformity of the report with the discipline’s current perception of climate change. The emphasis upon producing reports which reflect the consensus within a discipline has resulted in numerous charges that the IPCC’s warnings are inherently too conservative (Herrando-Pérez et al., 2019, Brysse et al., 2013).

Figure 1: The IPCC’s graphic laying out the publication and review process behind its reports


But the main weaknesses with the IPCC’s methodology are firstly that, in economics, it exclusively selects Neoclassical economists, and secondly, because there is no built-in review of one discipline’s findings by another, the conclusions of these Neoclassical economists about the dangers of climate change are reviewed only by other Neoclassical economists. The economic sections of IPCC reports are therefore unchallenged by other disciplines who also contribute to the IPCC’s reports.

Given the extent to which economists dominate the formation of most government policies in almost all fields, and not just strictly economic policy (Fourcade et al., 2015, Hirschman and Berman, 2014, Christensen, 2018, Lazear, 2000), the otherwise acceptable process by which the IPCC collates human knowledge on climate change has critically weakened, rather than strengthened, human society’s response to climate change. This is because, commencing with “Nobel Laureate” (Mirowski, 2020) William Nordhaus, the economists who specialise on climate change have falsely trivialized the dangers that climate change poses to human civilization.


Nobel Oblige

In his 2018 Nobel Prize lecture, William Nordhaus described a trajectory that would lead to global temperatures peaking at 4°C above pre-industrial levels in 2145 as “optimal” (Nordhaus, 2018a, Slide 6) because, according to his calculations, the damages from climate change over time, plus the abatement costs over time, are minimised on this trajectory. He estimated the discounted cost of the economic damages from unabated climate change — which would see temperatures approach 6°C above pre-industrial levels by 2150 — at $24 trillion, whereas the 4°C trajectory had damages of about $15 trillion and abatement costs of about $3 trillion. Trajectories with lower peak temperatures had higher abatement costs that overwhelmed the benefits (Nordhaus, 2018a, Slide 7). In a subsequent paper, Nordhaus claimed that even a 6°C increase would only reduce global income by only 7.9%, compared to what it would be in the complete absence of global warming.

This sanguine assessment of the costs of climate change contrasts starkly with the non-economic sections of IPCC reports. The recent Global Warming of 1.5°C Report, for example, predicted that 70% of insects and 40–60% of mammals would lose 50% or more of their range at 4.5°C (Warren et al., 2018, p. 792). Yet the economic components of IPCC reports concur with Nordhaus that damages from climate change will be slight: the Executive Summary of Chapter 10 of the 2014 Fifth Assessment, “Key Economic Sectors and Services”, opens with the declaration that:

For most economic sectors, the impact of climate change will be small relative to the impacts of other drivers (medium evidence, high agreement). Changes in population, age, income, technology, relative prices, lifestyle, regulation, governance, and many other aspects of socioeconomic development will have an impact on the supply and demand of economic goods and services that is large relative to the impact of climate change. (Arent et al., 2014a, p. 662)

How can such relatively small estimates of economic damages be reconciled with the large impacts that scientists expect on critical components of the biosphere? The answer is that they can’t, because the economic studies are not based on the scientific assessments of damage from climate change. Instead, the numerical estimates of the impact of climate change on GDP have been made up by economists themselves. I use the expression “made up” advisedly, because there is no more accurate way to characterise how Neoclassical economists have approached climate change. Before I explain how these spurious estimates were manufactured, it is useful to contrast them with some of the more easily understood dangerous consequences of a higher global average temperature.


The scientific assessment

Using Nordhaus’s sanguine prediction of a mere 7.9% reduction in global income from a 6°C increase (Nordhaus, 2018b, p. 345) as a reference point, three of the most obvious threats of a 6°C warmer world are the impact of these temperatures on human physiology, on the survival of other animals, and on the structure of the Earth’s atmospheric circulation systems.

A critical feature of human physiology is our ability to dissipate internal heat by perspiration. To do so, the external air needs to be colder than our ideal body temperature of about 37°C, and dry enough to absorb our perspiration as well. This becomes impossible when the combination of heat and humidity, known as the “wet bulb temperature”, exceeds 35°C. Above this level, we are unable to dissipate the heat generated by our bodies, and the accumulated heat will kill a healthy individual within three hours. Scientists have estimated that a 3.8°C increase in the global average temperature would make Jakarta’s temperature and humidity combination permanently fatal for humans, while a 5.5°C increase would mean that even New York would experience 55 days per year when the combination of temperature and humidity would be deadly (Mora et al., 2017, Figure 4, p. 504).

Temperature also affects the viable range for all biological organisms on the planet. Scientists have estimated that a 4.5°C increase in global temperatures would reduce the area of the planet in which life could exist by 40% or more, with the decline in the liveable area of the planet ranging from a minimum of 30% for mammals to a maximum of 80% for insects (Warren et al., 2018, Figure 1, p. 792).

The Earth’s current climate has three major air circulation systems in each hemisphere: a “Hadley Cell” between the Equator and 30°, a mid-latitude cell between 30° and 60°, and a Polar cell between 60° and 90°. This structure is why there is such large differences in temperature between the tropics, temperate and arctic regions, and relatively small differences within each region. Scientists have modelled the stability of these cells and concluded that they could be tipped, by an average global temperature increase of 4.3°C or more, into a state with just one cell in the Northern Hemisphere — and an average Arctic temperature of 22.5°C. This abrupt transition (known as a bifurcation), sometime in the next century would disrupt agriculture, plant, animal and human life across the planet, and would occur far too quickly for any meaningful adaptation, by natural and human systems alike (Kypke et al., 2020, Figure 6 p. 399).

These three factors and many others, caused not only by industry’s CO2 emissions but also by the myriad other ways we damage the biosphere, would occur together, and interact with each other, at temperature levels of 4–6°C above pre-industrial levels. Nordhaus’s assertion that such devastating changes to the Earth’s climate would reduce global GDP by less than 8%, compared to a world without climate change (Nordhaus, 2018b, p. 345), is simply risible. How could he arrive at such an absurd conclusion?

In common with most of my peers in non-Neoclassical economics, I initially assumed that the answer was that he applied far too high a “discount rate” to future damages (Hickel, 2018). If you think that 99% of the economy would be destroyed in a century from now by the catastrophic effects of a 6°C increase in temperatures, but discount that back to today’s world at a rate of 7% p.a., you get the result that this collapse in future GDP is worth only 0.1% of today’s GDP — which is no big deal.

If this had been how Nordhaus had arrived at such low damage estimate, then the high discount rate could be challenged, but the rest of his analysis could potentially be sound. But our guess was wrong. Nordhaus explained why he used a high discount rate when he strongly criticised the lower discount rate used by the Stern Review (Stern, 2007). It was not to reduce future catastrophic damages to trivial levels now, but because, if he used a low discount rate, then:

the relatively small damages in the next two centuries get overwhelmed by the high damages over the centuries and millennia that follow 2200. (Nordhaus, 2007, p. 202. Emphasis added)

“Relatively small damages in the next two centuries”? How on Earth did he reach that conclusion? I found out, to my disgust, that he and his colleagues ignored or distorted the work of scientists, and instead made up their own trivial estimates of the economic damage from climate change. I have spent fifty years of my life being a critic of Neoclassical economics. Neoclassical work on climate change is by far the lowest grade work that I have read in that half-century.


Reading Catastrophe and Seeing Utopia

I am accustomed to shaking my head in wonder at the capacity of Neoclassical economists to come up with ludicrous assumptions to jump over some logical impasse, like this gem by the developer of the Capital Assets Pricing Model, William Sharpe. After meticulously deriving a model of an individual “rational” investor, Sharpe then proceeded to model the entire market by assuming:

homogeneity of investor expectations: investors are assumed to agree on the prospects of various investments — the expected values, standard deviations and correlation coefficients described in Part II. (Sharpe, 1964, pp. 433–34, Fama and French, 2004, p. 26)

This is patently absurd. But at least Sharpe conceded as much, when he attempted to justify it via a clumsy rendition of Milton Friedman’s dodgy methodological defence of absurd assumptions (Friedman, 1953). Fama, who led the empirical defence of this theory (Fama, 1970, Fama and French, 1996, Fama and French, 2004), fitted it to actual stock market data, which for a time appeared to support the theory.

But in this work on climate change, Neoclassical economists have fitted their absurd-assumptions models to their own manifestly absurd made-up data. When they consulted scientists or referenced scientific literature, they frequently distorted the research or drowned the warnings of scientists with the blasé expectations of economists. This was nowhere more evident than in Nordhaus’s treatment of a key paper on the likelihood that global warming will trigger “tipping points” that cause runaway climate change, “Tipping elements in the Earth’s climate system” (Lenton et al., 2008).

Lenton’s paper considered whether there were large-scale elements of Earth’s climactic system which could be triggered into a qualitative change that would in turn rapidly alter the climate. He and his co-authors identified nine such systems (all but one of which — the Indian Monsoon — could be tipped by temperature increases alone), after applying the conditions that these systems had to be “subsystems of the Earth system that are at least subcontinental in scale” which could be “switched — under certain circumstances — into a qualitatively different state by small perturbations”. They excluded “systems in which any threshold appears inaccessible this century” (Lenton et al., 2008, pp. 1786–87).

If “Tipping elements” exist, and if they can be triggered by a temperature rise that can be expected from Global Warming this century, and if they would have drastic impacts upon the global climate, then the only prudent thing to do is to avoid such a temperature rise in the first place. If that rise occurs and a climactic element is tipped, it will unleash forces that will be far too large for human action to reverse. A qualitatively different climate would result, whose consequences for human civilisation cannot be predicted by extrapolating from what we know about our current climate.

Lenton and his co-authors identified two definite candidates for a tipping point this century — “Arctic sea-ice and the Greenland ice sheet” — and noted that “at least five other elements could surprise us by exhibiting a nearby tipping point” (Lenton et al., 2008, p. 1792) before 2100. They could not at the time specify a critical value for the temperature at which the decline in Arctic summer sea-ice would tip the Arctic from being a reflector of solar energy to an absorber, but noted that “a summer ice-loss threshold, if not already passed, may be very close and a transition could occur well within this century” (Lenton et al., 2008, p. 1789).

Nordhaus “summarised” this research with the sentence:

“Their review finds no critical tipping elements with a time horizon less than 300 years until global temperatures have increased by at least 3°C” (Nordhaus, 2013a, p. 60)

This is a total fabrication. Lenton’s careful definition itself contradicts Nordhaus’s alleged summary, by explicitly excluding systems which could not be triggered this century. Nordhaus’s claim that they found no systems which could be triggered in the next three centuries is false: they identified at least two, and possibly seven (out of eight!), which could be — though the process of transiting from their current to final states could take several centuries. Nordhaus claimed that the minimum temperature rise that could trigger a “critical tipping element” was 3°C: they said that Arctic summer sea-ice could be triggered with a rise of as little as 0.5°C — a level we have already well and truly exceeded.

There are few — if any — scientific or economic issues that are more important than this. It deserves the closest possible attention. And yet, if an undergraduate student of mine had summarised this paper as Nordhaus did, I would have failed him. However, since I was reading the work of a “Nobel Prize winner”, rather than an unsatisfactory undergraduate, I found myself having to do forensic research to work how on Earth Nordhaus could have reached his interpretation of this paper — which explicitly warned against using “smooth projections of global change”, and which explicitly warned of a likely tipping point in the Arctic — as supporting him trivialising the significance of losing Arctic summer sea-ice, and using a “damage function” that ignored tipping points (see Table 1).

Table 1: The chasm between Lenton’s conclusion and Nordhaus’s interpretation of this research


The only feasible explanation for Nordhaus’s erroneous summary was a table by Lenton in a related publication (Richardson et al., 2011), which Nordhaus also referenced as a source for his interpretation (Nordhaus, 2013b, p. 334). Lenton described this table as “A simple ‘straw man’ example of tipping element risk assessment”. Each “tipping element” was given a point score in terms of likelihood of occurring this century (Low=1, Medium=1.5, Medium-High=2.5, and High=3) and relative impact on the climate over the next millennium (Low=1, Low-Medium=1.5, Medium=2, Medium-High=2.5, and High=3). A risk score was derived as the product of likelihood times impact. Arctic summer sea-ice had the lowest rating on impact (Low=1), but the highest in terms of likelihood (High=3), for an overall score of 3 — see Table 2, which ranks these tipping elements in the descending order of importance that Nordhaus gave them in his table N.1 (Nordhaus, 2013b, p. 333).

Table 2: Based on Lenton’s Table “A simple ‘straw man’ example of tipping element risk assessment, by Timothy M. Lenton” in (Richardson et al., 2011, p. 186), and Nordhaus’s Table N-1, with his ranking of tipping elements used to sort the table (Nordhaus, 2013b, p. 333)


It appears that Nordhaus’s relative ranking was based primarily on Lenton’s “Impact” measure, since he ranked Arctic summer sea-ice as the lowest (one star in his Table N.1, or a low ranking of 3 in Table 2), below disrupting the Atlantic Thermohaline Circulation (THC) for example (two stars, or a medium ranking of 2), whereas Lenton ranked Arctic sea-ice above the THC in risk assessment terms (3 versus 2.5, where a higher score is worse) because of its much higher likelihood of occurring this century.

This may explain how Nordhaus came to classify losing the Arctic summer sea-ice as an event of low concern in climate change. But this is a false reading of Lenton’s table. As Lenton explained, “Impacts are considered in relative terms based on an initial subjective judgment (noting that most tipping-point impacts, if placed on an absolute scale compared to other climate eventualities, would be high)” (Richardson et al., 2011, p. 186. Emphasis added). In other words, while the impact of the loss of Arctic summer sea-ice was low compared to, for example, the impact of losing the Atlantic Thermohaline Circulation (THC), it was not low in any absolute sense: losing the Arctic’s summer sea-ice would have a significant qualitative impact on the climate. Nordhaus’s interpretation of Lenton’s “low” ranking as meaning that Arctic summer sea-ice was not of absolute importance to the climate — it was not “critical”, he alleged — is a fundamentally incorrect reading of Lenton’s research, as Lenton confirmed to me in personal correspondence (Keen and Lenton, 2020).

Nordhaus also misinterpreted the time ranges given (the “Transition Timescale” column in Table 2) as indicating that these tipping elements were not going to be triggered for that many years, when in fact they were an estimate of how long it would take from an initial triggering this century until the end of the transition process. The complete melting of the West Antarctic ice sheet might well take 300 years from its initial triggering, whereas the Arctic summer sea-ice could disappear over a period measured in decades rather than centuries. But the fate of the West Antarctic ice sheet would be decided this century, if we let increased CO2 levels drive up global temperature by 3°C or more — which we are well on track to do, and which we would reach on Nordhaus’s “optimum” trajectory by 2085.

In summary, Nordhaus read Lenton’s research as a climate change denier would, cherry picking it to find ways to support his preconception that climate change was insignificant. This was a consistent theme in Nordhaus’s treated scientific research on climate change, as evidenced by surveys he undertook of scientists in 1994 (Nordhaus, 1994), and scientific literature in 2017 (Nordhaus and Moffat, 2017).


Drowning Scientists with Economists

Nordhaus’s 1994 survey asked people from various academic backgrounds to give their estimates of the impact on GDP of three global warming scenarios, including a 3°C rise by 2090. The 2014 IPCC Report used this as one data point in Figure 10.1 (see Figure 2), claiming that a 3°C temperature rise would cause a 3.6% fall in GDP.

Nordhaus’s surveyed 19 people, 18 of whom fully complied, and one partially. Nordhaus described them as including 10 economists, 4 “other social scientists”, and 5 “natural scientists and engineers”, noting that eight of the economists come from “other subdisciplines of economics (those whose principal concerns lie outside environmental economics)” (Nordhaus, 1994, p. 48). This, ipso facto, should rule them out from taking part in this expert survey in the first place.

There was extensive disagreement between the relatively tiny cohort of actual scientists surveyed, and, in particular, the economists “whose principal concerns lie outside environmental economics”. As Nordhaus noted, “Natural scientists’ estimates [of the damages from climate change] were 20 to 30 times higher than mainstream economists’” (Nordhaus, 1994, p. 49). The average estimate by “Non-environmental economists” (Nordhaus, 1994, Figure 4, p. 49) of the damages to GDP a 3°C rise by 2090 was 0.4% of GDP; the average for natural scientists was 12.3%, and this was with one of them refusing to answer Nordhaus’s key questions:

“I must tell you that I marvel that economists are willing to make quantitative estimates of economic consequences of climate change where the only measures available are estimates of global surface average increases in temperature. As [one] who has spent his career worrying about the vagaries of the dynamics of the atmosphere, I marvel that they can translate a single global number, an extremely poor surrogate for a description of the climatic conditions, into quantitative estimates of impacts of global economic conditions.” (Nordhaus, 1994, pp. 50–51)

Comments from economists lay at the other end of the spectrum from this self-absented scientist. Because they had a strong belief in the ability of human economies to adapt, they could not imagine that climate change could do significant damage to the economy, whatever it might do to the biosphere itself:

There is a clear difference in outlook among the respondents, depending on their assumptions about the ability of society to adapt to climatic changes. One was concerned that society’s response to the approaching millennium would be akin to that prevalent during the Dark Ages, whereas another respondent held that the degree of adaptability of human economies is so high that for most of the scenarios the impact of global warming would be “essentially zero”. (Nordhaus, 1994, pp. 48–49. Emphasis added)

Given this extreme divergence of opinion between economists and scientists, one might expect that Nordhaus’s next survey would examine the reasons for it. In fact, the opposite applied: his methodology excluded non-economists entirely.

Rather than a survey of experts, this was a literature survey (Nordhaus and Moffat, 2017). He and his co-author searched for relevant articles using the string “”(damage OR impact) AND climate AND cost” (Nordhaus and Moffat, 2017, p. 7), which is reasonable, if too broad (as they admit in the paper).

The key flaw in this research was where they looked: they executed their search string in Google, which returned 64 million results, Google Scholar, which returned 2.8 million, and the economics-specific database Econlit, which returned just 1700 studies. On the grounds that there were too many results in Google and Google Scholar, they ignored those results, and simply surveyed the 1700 articles in Econlit (Nordhaus and Moffat, 2017, p. 7). These are, almost exclusively, articles written by economists. They did not search a comparable science database like ProQuest Science Journals, where the same too-broad search string (on January 11th 2021) returned 60,315 peer-reviewed full-text articles, and a narrower search string “damage AND climate AND gdp” returned a manageable 2,721 hits.

There is therefore no significant science-based content in the papers that generated the “data” on which IPCC economists concluded that “the impact of climate change will be small relative to the impacts of other drivers” (Arent et al., 2014a, p. 662). All of the pairs of numbers in Figure 2 were generated by economists, and all but one predict an extremely small impact on GDP from global warming, of a less than 3% fall in GDP from temperature rises of up to 3°C (or a 6% fall for a 5.5°C rise), compared to what GDP would be in the complete absence of climate change.

Figure 2: IPCC economic estimates of damages to GDP from global warming (Arent et al., 2014a, p. 690)


These numbers were generated in two main ways, which the IPCC report described as “Enumeration” and “Statistical” (Arent et al., 2014b, Table SM10.2, p. SM10–4). Enumeration added up estimates of damages to industries from climate change, under the assumption that only activities exposed to the weather would be affected; the “statistical” method used the weak correlation between average temperature and average income today as a proxy for the impact of climate change over time.


Equating Climate with Weather

Nordhaus’s first predictions of the economic consequences of climate change in a refereed journal — the Economic Journal — came in 1991. This paper, entitled “To Slow or Not to Slow: The Economics of The Greenhouse Effect” (Nordhaus, 1991) contained the seeds of all his future work on climate change. He equated climate change over time, due to dramatically increasing the amount of solar radiation retained in the biosphere as heat by increased greenhouse gases, with the geographic variation of today’s climate across the globe:

human societies thrive in a wide variety of climatic zones. For the bulk of economic activity, non-climate variables like labour skills, access to markets, or technology swamp climatic considerations in determining economic efficiency. (Nordhaus, 1991, p. 930)

He assumed that climate change would only affect economic activities that were directly exposed to the weather:

The most sensitive sectors are likely to be those, such as agriculture and forestry, in which output depends in a significant way upon climatic variables… Our estimate is that approximately 3% of United States national output is produced in highly sensitive sectors, another 10% in moderately sensitive sectors, and about 87 % in sectors that are negligibly affected by climate change. (Nordhaus, 1991, Table 5, p. 930. Emphasis added)

Table 3: Extract from Nordhaus’s breakdown of economic activity by vulnerability to climatic change (Nordhaus, 1991, p. 931)


Using these beliefs, he derived trivial estimates for the impact of climate change on the economy:

damage from a 3°C warming is likely to be around ¼% of national income in United States … We might raise the number to around 1% of total global income to allow for these unmeasured and unquantifiable factors, although such an adjustment is purely ad hoc… my hunch is that the overall impact upon human activity is unlikely to be larger than 2% of total output. (Nordhaus, 1991, p. 933)

All subsequent papers by Neoclassical climate-change economists replicated the assumption that any activity not directly exposed to the weather would be immune from climate change. The 2014 IPCC Report restated it as a “Frequently Asked Question”:


FAQ 10.3 | Are other economic sectors vulnerable to climate change too?

Economic activities such as agriculture, forestry, fisheries, and mining are exposed to the weather and thus vulnerable to climate change. Other economic activities, such as manufacturing and services, largely take place in controlled environments and are not really exposed to climate change. (Arent et al., 2014a, p. 688. Emphasis added)


Equating Time with Space

Nordhaus’s colleague Robert Mendelsohn (Mendelsohn et al., 1994, Mendelsohn et al., 2000) used Nordhaus’s assumption that today’s climate and GDP data was relevant to climate change to invent another way to predict the impact of global warming from today’s data:

An alternative approach … can be called the statistical approach. It is based on direct estimates of the welfare impacts, using observed variations (across space within a single country) in prices and expenditures to discern the effect of climate. Mendelsohn assumes that the observed variation of economic activity with climate over space holds over time as well; and uses climate models to estimate the future effect of climate change. (Tol, 2009, p. 32. Emphasis added)

This method of generating numbers takes average temperature data and per capita income data, and uses the weak correlation between them to allege that climate change will be relatively trivial. Figure 3 shows temperature and per capita income for the contiguous United States on a State-by-State basis (“Gross State Product per capita”, or GSPPC).

Figure 3: Correlation of temperature and USA Gross State Product per capita


There is no real pattern, but a quadratic can be fitted to the data as shown, with a low correlation coefficient of 0.31. In statistical terms, this means that this function has terrible predictive power. For example, it predicts that States which are 4°C hotter or colder than the USA average will have a GSPPC that is 5% lower. But the states that are between 3.5°C and 4.5°C above or below the USA’s average temperatures include New York at 30% above the average, and Arkansas at 29% below. If you were trying to win a game of Trivial Pursuit, you wouldn’t use this function to supply your answers on US GSP per capita today.


Trivial estimates of serious damages

And yet Nordhaus uses a quadratic, derived from data much like that in Figure 3, but with an even smaller coefficient, to “predict” the impact of Global Warming on “Gross Global Product” (GGP). The equation of the quadratic in Figure 3 is . Nordhaus’s “damage function”, in the latest version of his global warming model DICE (for “Dynamic Integrated Climate and Economics”), is :

The parameter used in the model was an equation with a parameter of 0.227 percent loss in global income per degrees Celsius squared with no linear term. This leads to a damage of 2.0 percent of income at 3°C, and 7.9 percent of global income at a global temperature rise of 6°C. (Nordhaus, 2018b, p. 345)

These predictions are absurd. A 3°C increase could trigger, and a 6°C increase would trigger, every “tipping element” shown in Table 2. The Earth would have a climate unlike anything our species has experienced in its existence, and the Earth would transition to it hundreds of times faster than it has in any previous naturally-driven global warming event (McNeall et al., 2011). The Tropics and much of the globe’s temperate zone would be uninhabitable by humans and most other life forms. And yet Nordhaus thinks it would only reduce the global economy by just 8%?

Comically, Nordhaus’s damage function is symmetricalit predicts the same damages from a fall in temperature as for an equivalent rise. It therefore predicts that a 6°C fall in global temperature would also reduce GGP by just 7.9% (see Figure 3). Unlike global warming, we do know what the world was like when the temperature was 6°C below 20th century levels: that was the average temperature of the planet during the last Ice Age (Tierney et al., 2020), which ended about 20,000 years ago. At the time, all of America north of New York, and of Europe north of Berlin, was beneath a kilometre of ice. The thought that a transition to such a climate in just over a century would cause global production to fall by less than 8% is laughable.

Again, I found myself in the position of a forensic detective, trying to work out how on Earth could otherwise intelligent people come to believe that climate change would only affect industries that are directly exposed to the weather, and that the correlation between climate today and economic output today across the globe could be used to predict the impact of global warming on the economy? The only explanation that made sense is that these economists were mistaking the weather for the climate. Ironically, given the calibre of Nordhaus’s later contributions, he gave a reasonable, if statistically-oriented, explanation of the difference between weather and climate in an early paper:

When we refer to climate, we usually are thinking of the average of characteristics of the atmosphere at different points of the earth, including the variances such as the diurnal and annual cycle. The important characteristics for man’s activities are temperature, precipitation, snow cover, winds and so forth. A more precise representation of the climate would be as a dynamic, stochastic system of equations. The probability distributions of the atmospheric characteristics is what we mean by climate, while a particular realization of that stochastic process is what we call the weather. (Nordhaus, 1976, p. 2)

This “probability distribution”, as we experience it at any given location on Earth, is affected by the amount of energy in the biosphere, which varies in three primary ways:
  1. Variations in the amount of the energy from the Sun that reaches the Earth;
  2. Variations in the amount of this energy retained by greenhouse gases; and
  3. Variations caused by differences in location on the planet — primarily, differences in distance from the Equator, altitude above sea level, and distance from oceans.

The first factor varies, via cyclical variations in the Earth’s orbit, over time measured in thousands of years, and via long-term trends in the Sun’s evolution, measured in billions of years. Neither of these are relevant in the timeframe of global warming. Given the Earth’s orbit, and how much its surface reflects solar radiation, then in the absence of the second factor — greenhouse gases — the average temperature of the atmosphere would be minus 18°C (Hay, 2014, p. 30, Galimov, 2017).

The second is what is at issue with global warming. If the Earth’s atmosphere captured and re-radiated all the infra-red energy that the planet’s surface reflects back into space (as a relatively dark body, the Earth absorbs high-frequency light and ultra-violet energy from the Sun, and reflects back low-frequency infra-red energy), then the average temperature of the atmosphere would be 29.5°C. With only naturally-occurring greenhouse gases, the average temperature of the planet at present would be 15°C. Human industrial activity is adding to this retention of solar energy, primarily by generating additional CO2 from burning fossil fuels.

The third, geographic factor is what is captured by the data shown in Figure 3 — and this has nothing to do with global warming. And yet this data, plus the belief that only industries which are exposed to the weather will be affected by global warming, is what underpins Nordhaus’s “damage function” (and similar constructs by his fellow Neoclassical climate change economists) with its trivial forecasts for economic damage from climate change.

One thing that Figure 3 does establish is that wide variations in temperature within one country today are associated with relatively small differences in income today. The range of average temperatures shown there is 16.8°C, from 4.7°C for North Dakota to 21.5°C for Florida. However, the two States had very similar Gross State Products per capita in 2000 ($26,700 versus $26,000). This cannot be used to argue that, therefore, a huge change in global average temperatures due to global warming will have only a small effect on income — but that is precisely how Neoclassical economists have used this data.

That is evident in their predictions, but it helps to also have verbal confirmation of the disconnect between what economists think of climate change, and what it really is. The following statements were made on Twitter by the prominent Neoclassical climate change economist Richard Tol. Tol was one of the two lead co-authors of the economic sections of the 2014 IPCC report on climate change (Arent et al., 2014a), the developer of FUND (“Climate Framework for Uncertainty, Negotiation and Distribution”), one of “Integrated Assessment models” (IAMs) used to supposedly estimate the impact of climate change on the economy, and editor of the academic journal Energy Economics. However, his arguments are those one would with associate with an ignorant troll, not an influential economist in the theory and practice of climate change.

In the first tweet, he concludes that climate change is not a problem, because US States with vastly different temperatures today have similar incomes today:

10K is less than the temperature distance between Alaska and Maryland (about equally rich), or between Iowa and Florida (about equally rich). Climate is not a primary driver of income. https://twitter.com/RichardTol/status/1140591420144869381?s=20

In the second, he concludes that global warming can’t be a problem, because it is expected to increase temperatures by a small amount compared to the daily temperature variation for any one location on Earth — which averages about 14°C for the continental USA (Qu et al., 2014):

People thrive in a wide range of climates. The projected climate change is small relative to the diurnal cycle. It is therefore rather peculiar to conclude that climate change will be disastrous. Those who claim so have been unable to explain why. https://twitter.com/RichardTol/status/1313182006310731776?s=20

My personal experience of responding to delusional beliefs like these reminds me of the aphorism widely attributed to George Bernard Shaw, that “he who wrestles with a hog must expect to be spattered with filth, whether he is vanquished or not”. In contrast, this is how a key scientific paper (Im et al., 2017`) summarised what a world 4°C warmer — let alone 10°C-14°C warmer — would mean for the over 2 billion human inhabitants of South Asia:

Human exposure to TW [wet bulb temperatures] of around 35°C for even a few hours will result in death even for the fittest of humans under shaded, well-ventilated conditions… TWmax is projected to exceed the survivability threshold … under the RCP8.5 scenario by the end of the century over most of South Asia, including the Ganges river valley, northeastern India, Bangladesh, the eastern coast of India, Chota Nagpur Plateau, northern Sri Lanka, and the Indus valley of Pakistan. (Im et al., 2017, p. 4)


The failure of peer review

There is one generic defence of the failure of the referees of economic journals to identify this work as effectively fraudulent. Academics are not paid to referee, and the time they are supposedly allotted to do refereeing has been largely eliminated by the efficiency drives that politicians and the managerial class of University administrators have forced upon them. So refereeing is not done as professionally as the image of “peer reviewed research” implies. Refereeing is also a far lower standard than replication. To referee a paper, all a referee has to do is read it and pass judgment. To replicate, you actually have to independently reproduce the results claimed in the paper.

That said, there is no excuse for referees approving for publication papers that, for example, make the critical and absurd assumption that 87% of GDP will be unaffected by climate change, because it happens indoors (Nordhaus, 1991, p. 930). Here, the guilty party is not Nordhaus alone, but the entire edifice of Neoclassical economics. Only Neoclassical economists, who in general have what Paul Romer described as a “noncommittal relationship with the truth” (Romer, 2016, p. 5), would recommend publication of papers that make critical assumptions that are so obviously false.

As I detail in Debunking Economics (Keen, 2011), Neoclassical economics is riddled with false assumptions, because numerous theoretical and empirical requirements of the underlying theory have been proven to be false. Rather than accepting that their initial beliefs were wrong, and then abandoning these beliefs to develop a richer, more complex theory, Neoclassical economists have clung to those beliefs by adding patently absurd assumptions to hide the contrary proofs.

This practice is defended by describing such assumptions as “simplifying”, but that a false description. A simplifying assumption is something that, if it is false, complicates the analysis a great deal, but changes the result only marginally. For example, Galileo’s demonstration that dense bodies fall at the same speed, regardless of their weight, effectively assumed no air resistance. Taking air resistance into account would have resulted in a vastly more complicated demonstration, but no significant change in the result.

On the other hand, the type of assumption that Neoclassical economists defend as “simplifying” is frequently critical to the conclusions drawn from the model: if the assumption is false, then so are the conclusions (Musgrave, 1990). Such assumptions abound in Neoclassical economics, so much so that economists have convinced themselves that it is invalid to criticise a theory on the grounds that its assumptions are unrealistic:

To put this point less paradoxically, the relevant question to ask about the “assumptions” of a theory is not whether they are descriptively “realistic”, for they never are, but whether they are sufficiently good approximations for the purpose in hand. And this question can be answered only by seeing whether the theory works, which means whether it yields sufficiently accurate predictions. (Friedman, 1953, p. 153)

This, as Alan Musgrave explained, is nonsense (Musgrave, 1981). However, because they accept Friedman’s dodgy methodology, Neoclassical referees regularly recommend the publication of papers in which assumptions are made that are patently false, if those papers support Neoclassical beliefs. To such referees, Nordhaus’s assumption that “87% [of United States national output is produced] in sectors that are negligibly affected by climate change” (Nordhaus, 1991, p. 930) was just a “simplifying assumption”, which could not be challenged.

This methodological fallacy is dangerous enough with standard economic issues. But with climate change, it is existentially so. When the theory is proven wrong by the failure of its predictions, the consequences of this failure will be both catastrophic and irreversible. As DeCanio eloquently put it, waiting until we know that Neoclassical economists are wrong on climate change “amounts to conducting a one-time, irreversible experiment of unknown outcome with the habitability of the entire planet” (DeCanio, 2003, p. 3).


Conclusion

Neoclassical economics has dominated economics for 150 years, which has given it the advantage of incumbency over its rivals — so much so that most people in authority, journalists, University students, and the general public, think that Neoclassical economics is economics. When it is criticised, even by other economists like myself (Keen, 2011), the public is unlikely to hear the criticisms in the first place, and likely to regard them as coming from cranks if they do. Q-Anon aside, we trust those ordained as experts in their own fields.

This trust is a characteristic of human society which is utterly justified in the complex societies in which we live. Deference to expertise is a necessary feature of life in a complex world. However, with economics, this justifiable deference has helped entrench a fundamentally unscientific school of thought, and has made progress in economics virtually impossible.

I believed, before the Global Financial Crisis, that the only way economics could be shifted would be by its failure to predict a serious economic crisis. But the transient nature of economic crises — especially in the face of governments determined not to let capitalism fail on their watch — meant that economic theory scraped through that crisis relatively unscathed. That may all change in the next decade, because our trust in expertise has meant that, though scientists led the study of climate change, we have let Neoclassical economists determine our policy response.

Most politicians have studied some economics. Few have studied science, and they are therefore unable to read the science-based parts of the IPCC Reports. Most of their advisers — who actually read the reports for the politicians — are also trained in economics, rather than the sciences. Most political debate is about matters of economics, rather than science. The end result of all this is that, though scientists have led the study of climate change itself, economists have dominated public policy towards it. As Stephen De Canio put it in 2003:

it is undeniably the case that economic arguments, claims, and calculations have been the dominant influence on the public political debate on climate policy in the United States and around the world… It is an open question whether the economic arguments were the cause or only an ex-post justification of the decisions made … but there is no doubt that economists have claimed that their calculations should dictate the proper course of action. (DeCanio, 2003, p. 4)

Because these economists, starting with William Nordhaus, trivialised the dangers of climate change, the policy response to climate change has also been trivial. Human civilisation may well not survive Neoclassical economics. It’s time it was eliminated, before it eliminates us.